Can Shinzō Abe boost Japan’s economy?

Over at Slate, Matthew Yglesias made the argument last week that the likely victory of former prime minister Shinzō Abe (安倍 晋三) and the return of the Liberal Democratic Party of Japan (LDP, or 自由民主党, Jiyū-Minshutō) to government after a three-year hiatus means that Japan might finally embark on a path of more expansionary monetary policy — namely, more quantitative easing and a higher inflation target. Japan

With Japan apparently headed back into a recession — its fifth in 15 years — that strategy could be the surest way to boost the Japanese economy, but it’s a little naive to believe Abe can command enough political support, even with a landslide victory in Sunday’s election, to dictate monetary policy to the Bank of Japan.

Earlier in the campaign, Abe pledged to force the Bank of Japan to purchase construction bonds directly from the Japanese government (although, as Yglesias notes, Abe has already backed down from that pledge during the campaign).  Abe needs the BOJ to buy those bonds in order to finance additional infrastructure spending, with the LDP calling for up to ¥200 trillion ($2.4 trillion) in public works over the next decade.  Public spending is an old LDP favorite, but that staggering amount of spending could well pull Japan’s economy out of recession and deflation.

Abe has also pledged to appoint a new bank governor — the term of the current Bank of Japan governor Masaaki Shirakawa (白川 方明) ends in April 2013 after five years heading the BOJ — who agrees to set an annual inflation target of 2% or even 3%.

Abe’s push for expansionary fiscal and monetary policy comes as a bit of a 180-degree turn, given that the third and final government of the Democratic Party of Japan (DPJ, or 民主党, Minshutō) under prime minister Yoshihiko Noda (野田 佳彦) recently expended its last gasp of governing willpower to double Japan’s consumption tax from 5% to 10%, which is scheduled to begin in 2014.

It seems much likelier that Abe could implement a new round of fiscal expansion than strong-arm the Bank of Japan, which has an extraordinary amount of central bank independence — derived in part from the memory of hyperinflation that resulted after World War II when politicians controlled monetary policy decisions.

Noda (pictured above, right, with Abe) has attacked Abe’s platform as a dangerous intrusion on central bank independence and he has attacked the LDP plan for additional debt-financed spending as the same old LDP  ‘baramaki’ (pork barrel) politics, especially given Japan’s debt-to-GDP ratio is already, by far, the world’s largest, at around 230%.  Greece, by the way, has only a 160% ratio.

Japan has traditionally been able to carry such a high ratio because much of that debt is held by its citizens, who collective have one of the top savings rates in the industrialized world, but with $13.64 trillion in debt already on its public books, it’s not clear whether Japan could sustain public spending that would boost its debt-to-GDP ratio to nearly 300%.

As Yglesias notes, the Bank of Japan has been criticized for nearly two decades for its policy to keep Japan’s inflation target at zero:

Back in 1999, Ben Bernanke condemned the self-induced paralysis of Japanese monetary policy made by flailing officials who claimed it was beyond their power to fix this. He called for “Rooseveltian resolve” on the part of Japan’s leaders to shake the bank out of its torpor.  Paul Krugman, too, spent the late ’90s urging Japan to aim for more inflation, arguing that mucking around with the banking system was inadequate and weird delusions of respectability were holding policymakers back.

As Yglesias also notes, Europeans and Americans promptly forgot that advice when the 2008 financial crisis exploded budget deficits:

Suddenly, criticizing the Bank of Japan went out of style. America became Japan and simultaneously forgot what America used to think about Japan.

But perhaps the lesson that Yglesias is forgetting — and the lesson that the 2008 crisis taught Europeans and Americans — is that politics matters, and that politics can intrude on what might otherwise be a clear policy path, whether it’s ‘fiscal cliff’ negotiations in the United States or the ‘kick-the-can’ politics of eurozone bailouts.

Yglesias is also forgetting that Japan has politics, too.

If the LDP returns to power in Sunday’s elections to the lower house of the Diet, it will be hardly less unified than when it was in power — the party remains very much a broad patchwork of competing factions, each with its own domestic and foreign policy preferences.  Although much of the LDP would surely welcome another tranche of debt-backed public spending, it’s not certain that the more reform-minded members of the LDP would necessarily go along with Abe’s plan.

The signature achievement of former LDP prime minister Junichiro Koizumi (小泉 純一郎), the breakup of Japan’s public-sector post office (also the country’s largest savings bank, insurance company and largest employer) was only possible after Koizumi called a snap election in 2005 to wage a campaign to win a mandate against members of his own party who opposed the reforms.

Furthermore, there’s also no guarantee that Abe would be able to pass any legislation in the House of Councillors, the upper house of the Diet, where the DPJ will still hold the largest share of seats until at least July 2013, when the next elections are due for the House of Councillors.  If Abe and the LDP’s traditional ally, the New Kōmeitō (公明党, Shin Kōmeitō), wins over 320 seats on Sunday (out of 480 total), they will have a veto-proof majority in the lower house, thereby allowing Abe to bypass the upper house’s objections.  But such a two-thirds majority would require the kind of discipline that’s eluded the LDP in past governments.

The average time in office of each of the past six prime ministers — three LDP and three DPJ — has been around 15 months (including Abe, who served exactly one year from 2006 to 2007).  The upper house election is just seven months away — around half of the average lifetime of recent governments.  So while Yglesias may be right that a burst of inflationary easing could well be the magic bullet that Japan needs, it’s not clear that Abe will have enough time to effect that change before Japan’s finicky and recession-worn electorate has its next chance to weigh in.

Maybe the Japan Restoration Party (日本維新の会, Nippon Ishin no Kai), the new odd-couple alliance of Osaka mayor Tōru Hashimoto (橋下徹) and former Tokyo governor Shintaro Ishihara (石原慎太郎), will win a sizable bloc of seats on Sunday and support Abe between now and next July.  Maybe it won’t.  No one really knows, because it’s unclear just where the party will end up on any policy, monetary or otherwise.

Since GDP growth peaked at just over 7% in 1988, Japan spent the 1990s and 2000s in a low-growth phase, with a high of 2.36% GDP growth in 2004, buoyed in part by the privatization of Japan’s behemoth post office and other structural reforms pursued by Koizumi.  The economy contracted by 5.5% in 2009 and shot back up with 4% growth in 2010, but has essentially returned to form, with an economy that remains perched sluggishly on the line between zero-growth and narrow recession.

2 thoughts on “Can Shinzō Abe boost Japan’s economy?”

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *